When trying to increase your pay was dangerous

Andy Haldane’s speech in Bradford this week made headlines because of his comments about interest rates but what he said about stagnating wages is much more interesting.

He looked at the evolution of the Phillips curve, which shows the relationship between wage inflation and unemployment. In what we used to think of as normal times, if unemployment went up, wages fell. As demand for labour picked up, the reverse happened  because employers had to pay more to attract people from a shrinking pool of labour. Worker bargaining power increased as unemployment fell and reduced as it rose.

At least, that’s what used to happen. As Mr Haldane said, somewhat mischievously:

Historically, there has been a reasonably strong and stable relationship between unemployment and wage growth – the so-called Phillips curve. As unemployment has fallen recently, this Phillips curve relationship would have led us to expect wage growth to pick up. That, plainly, has not happened. Over recent years, the Phillips curve relationship has been anything but strong and stable (Chart 3).

In the last couple of decades, and especially since the recession, the unemployment rate doesn’t seem to have had much impact on wages at all. Whatever else has happened, pay has stagnated.

Something similar, seems to have happened before the industrial revolution. The data we have available seem to indicate that there was a long period before the industrial revolution when there was little wage inflation and not much of a link between pay and unemployment. The Phillips curve for this period was also flat.

Chart 11 plots UK Phillips curves over three periods: 1500-1700 (pre-Industrial Revolution); 1860-1950 (post-Industrial Revolution); 1950-1977 and 1977 to date (post-war period). In each case, wage inflation is measured on the y-axis and an estimate of the output gap on the x-axis. In the post-war period, the Phillips curve conforms to type. Since 1950, it has a clearly positive slope (less slack in the economy is associated with higher wage inflation) and an intercept which is positive (reflecting positive trend inflation).

The post-Industrial Revolution Phillips curve has a conventional upward slope, similar to that operating after 1950. Higher growth or lower unemployment is associated with higher rates of wage and price inflation. The pre-Industrial Revolution Phillips curve is altogether different; it is as flat as a pancake. Indeed, it bears a close resemblance to the Phillips curves which have operated, in the UK and globally, since 2008.

Could we be seeing a return to the power imbalances of the pre-industrial period? The pattern of the last few years, says Mr Haldane, looks remarkably similar to that of pre-industrial Britain:

The move towards greater self-employment and less unionisation is, in some respects, a shift back to the future in the nature of work. Prior to the Industrial Revolution, and indeed for some years after it, most workers were self-employed or worked in small businesses. There were no unions. Hours were flexible, depending on what work was needed to collect the crops, milk the cows or put bread on the table. Work was artisanal, task-based, divisible.

While the read-across to work patterns in the 21st century is far from exact, there are some parallels. That being the case, one question is how wage- and price-setting behaviour operated during this earlier period of more “divisible” labour markets. Were any of today’s wage patterns evident then? The data we have on wages and output in earlier centuries are partial and imperfect, but nonetheless tell an interesting story.

The difficulty he identifies in comparing today’s work patterns with those of the 18th and 19th centuries may go some way to answering his question. As Simon Deakin said, employment contracts are a 20th century development. Our forebears would not have understood work relationships in the same terms. From the 16th century until 1875, employment was governed by master and servant law. The feudal idea that workers were bound to their masters was a long time dying.

In today’s language, probably the best way of understanding employment under master and servant law is as a series of fixed-term contracts. These could vary in length and often started and finished on quarter days. In theory, they gave a measure of security to workers who would at least know that they had a job until Michaelmas. In practice, as Professor Deakin explains, the courts often found that, while the worker was bound to the employer, the employer was not bound to provide work or wages:

The employer was found to have an implied right to lay off without wages, even in the case of an annual pit bond binding the workers to a year’s exclusive service. In this sense, long- service agreements effectively benefited only the employer; the worker was bound without having the protection of security of income or employment.

To make life that bit more difficult for the workers, they didn’t even have the same rights in court as their masters. As Paul Johnson points out:

A master sued by a worker could be a witness in his own defence, but until 1867 a worker prosecuted by an employer could not give any evidence on his own behalf.

But the power imbalance doesn’t stop there. Under master and servant law, workers were subject to criminal sanctions for breaches of their contracts while masters were only subject to the civil law. In cases of breaches of contract, workers had to pursue employers through the courts, while employers had the entire apparatus of criminal law enforcement at their disposal.

According to Professor Johnson, there were around 10,000 prosecutions a year for breach of contract in the mid-19th century. These were concentrated in the industrial areas so the likelihood of a worker knowing someone who had been brought before the court was high:

The annual chance of a working-class household suffering criminal prosecution for breach of labour contract lay between 1 in 150 and 1 in 200 – a sufficiently high rate for knowledge of the risk to be well known within working class communities.

And, of course, where contracts were for a fixed term, breach of contract could simply mean leaving your employer for another job. Suresh Naidu and Noam Yuchtman studied the master and servant prosecutions during the nineteenth century and found that most were brought for absconding.

The typical goal of a prosecution was to use the threat of incarceration and hard labor to prevent workers from leaving an employer, and to pursue and punish those who were not deterred.

The threat of prosecution was credible; not only were prosecutions common but they were also largely successful.

The use of the word absconding reflects the attitudes of the time. Workers were deemed to be bound to their masters. Those who tried to improve their wages by looking for work elsewhere could expect severe punishment, backed up by the criminal law.

The penalties could be harsh and, during the late 18th and early 19th centuries, the Master and Servant Acts became more punitive. Usually workers were ordered back to their masters or were forced to pay compensation but in some cases imprisonment and even beatings could be imposed. The law was reformed in 1867, replacing the more brutal punishments with fines. However, as most of these workers were poor, the effect of a fine may simply have meant that they later ended up in prison for being unable to pay it.

Chart by Suresh Naidu and Noam Yuchtman

Perhaps unsurprisingly, Naidu and Yuchtman also noticed a relationship between the level of unemployment and the incidence of prosecutions:

[P]rosecutions and the unemployment rate move in opposite directions throughout the period for which we have data.

They also found that, once master and servant law was abolished in 1875, wages rose fastest in the counties with the highest rate of prosecutions.

This, then, might account for the different shape of the Phillips curve after 1860. Once criminal sanctions were removed for workers who tried to seek employment elsewhere, the labour market outcomes began to reflect supply and demand more closely. The rise of trade unions, who played a major role in the campaign to abolish master and servant law, increased the bargaining power of labour.

To put it another way, it is likely that Phillips curve was held flat until the 1860s by draconian labour laws. It is difficult enough for workers of limited means to challenge their employers at the best of times but laws preventing them from giving evidence against their employers and imprisoning them for leaving their jobs made for a very lopsided balance of power. Any countervailing power that falling unemployment might have given to the workers could be neutralised by the criminal law. Servants who got above themselves could, quite literally, be captured and brought back. If we think there is an imbalance of power in the workplace now, it’s nothing compared to the mid 19th century. In those days, trying to get a pay rise was a very dangerous game.

Advertisements
This entry was posted in Uncategorized. Bookmark the permalink.

10 Responses to When trying to increase your pay was dangerous

  1. Dipper says:

    The reason for this is blindingly obvious isn’t it? Free Movement of Labour?

    • Anarcho says:

      So nothing to do with, say, the Tory anti-union laws? It is blindingly obvious that this is the main reason…

      after all, there was immigration in the 1960s and 1970s but wages increased. The difference now is the onslaught on the trade unions since the 1980s and the most draconian anti-worker and anti-union laws in the western world.

      • Dipper says:

        It is very hard to escape supply and demand. I’m all for some more power to unions, particularly as Germany gets by fine with strong unions, but that power won’t achieve anything as long as employers can just draw on millions of workers at low rates.

        • John says:

          A Corbyn-led Labour Government could repeal anti-labour and anti-trades union laws.
          They could also restore the numbers of workplace inspectors to ensure safe working conditions and to ensure that all employers pay their workers a proper living wage.
          They could also promote investment so that small and medium sized enterprises end up with modern updated equipment and technology to enhance UK workers’ productivity.
          By restoring power back to labour, this will ensure that the division of wealth between labour and capital is more appropriately balanced.
          Allowing a few to hoard obscene levels of wealth does not help our society.

          • Dipper says:

            John – you can’t just mandate wealth and productivity. Even if the workplace inspectors were doing a good job they would still be a tax on the business. And how will the government “promote investment” in machinery and technology without this becoming a scheme for draining the government of money on unnecessary computers?

            Many working people on tax credits have effective marginal rates of taxation of over 90% making them working harder or longer pointless. Would you abolish the working tax credits to restore the incentive for workers to become more productive?

            And a Corbyn government would increase taxes, increasing Corporation tax and introducing taxes such as the Financial Transation Tax that would tax business activities. All these tax rises would reduce the incentive to generate wealth in businesses and hence pay workers more money.

            And whilst people becoming obscenely rich through exploiting others is not something to be praised, in Eastern Europe under communism there was a notable lack of obscenely rich people and that didn’t generate wealth for the masses. Isn’t complaining about the rich just a diversion from the hard job of generating wealth?

            Everyone wants to see workers becoming better off. There isn’t any reason to suppose that a Corbyn government simply commanding that everyone be better off is actually going to work, and lots of reasons to think that workers will be worse off due to their policies.

          • John says:

            With a centrally controlled and directed economy you can mandate wealth and productivity.
            The UK economy during World War Two achieved this in considerable measure.
            Following Brexit, similar powers will be available to UK governments.
            These powers – via fiscal policies and regional and national investment strategies – would work.
            Workplace inspectors are not a drain on the economy.
            They are guarantors of effective economic demand for purchasers of goods and services.
            They encourage good employers to promote their employees wellbeing, safety and with fairness.
            Getting rid of cowboy employers and operators can only benefit everyone.
            Naturally, businesses will have to meet relevant criteria to qualify for investment incentives.
            Can you provide evidence of anyone paying effective marginal rates of taxation of over 90%?
            The extra taxes reaped from businesses will represent only their fair share of taxes.
            Generating wealth is something that societies do – not individuals.
            Wealth – like manure – is no good unless it is spread around to yield yet more wealth.
            I don’t believe everyone wants working people to be better off – certainly not the Tories.
            They could not care less about working and former working people.
            That is why their former smug and arrogant leader Cameron had Brexit blow up in his face.
            The same issue looks likely to render the May administration apart sooner rather than later.
            The Tory policy of austerity has achieved only one thing: a vicious downward spiral for all.
            All, that is, with the exception of a tiny parasitic class of uber-wealthy individuals.
            They use their wealth to create a hegemonic set of values that support their greed.
            In the process, they appear to able to convert even intelligent people like you to their ideas.
            I don’t blame you entirely – the same class own and control the mass media.
            It is the mass media with their constantly repeated memes who end up controlling your mind.

  2. John says:

    There was also the provision of “tied” accommodation.
    Anyone leaving a job had also to leave their home.
    The church played a controlling role by recording who did – or did not – go to church on Sundays.
    Those who did not attend church services could risk losing their “tied” family homes.
    If we continue back to those days, will the sales of caps for doffing also increase?

  3. Paul Johnston says:

    Another great piece (as usual). Of course, one famous but rather surprising person to end up in prison for absconding from a contract of employment was J S Bach who spent several months in prison as a result. A man’s word should be his bond especially if he is a servant!

  4. Pingback: Links, 27 June 2017 | illiquid ideas

Leave a Reply

Fill in your details below or click an icon to log in:

WordPress.com Logo

You are commenting using your WordPress.com account. Log Out / Change )

Twitter picture

You are commenting using your Twitter account. Log Out / Change )

Facebook photo

You are commenting using your Facebook account. Log Out / Change )

Google+ photo

You are commenting using your Google+ account. Log Out / Change )

Connecting to %s